CATEGORII DOCUMENTE |
Bulgara | Ceha slovaca | Croata | Engleza | Estona | Finlandeza | Franceza |
Germana | Italiana | Letona | Lituaniana | Maghiara | Olandeza | Poloneza |
Sarba | Slovena | Spaniola | Suedeza | Turca | Ucraineana |
The Consumer Theory
How Consumers Make Choices under Income Constraints
Economists have, among other, the difficult task of understanding the way the average consumer behaves. Predicting how the increase in oil price, for example, will affect prices of other goods (food, services) is relatively an easier task for economists and psychologists along than predicting how a consumer will react to an increased price for a bottle of water or for an automobile. For this matter, a change with a certain percent in the original cost for two goods like those mentioned above will definitely be perceived as more obvious in the case of an automobile that in that of a bottle of water. Just think what a 10% increase means to a price around $10.000 and what a 10% increase means to $10!
* Some Questions
What is behind a consumers demand curve?
How do consumers choose from among various consumer goods?
What determines the value of a consumer good?
*Utility
Definition: The value a consumer places on a unit of a good or service depends on the pleasure or satisfaction he or she expects to derive from having or consuming it at the point of making a consumption (consumer) choice.
In economics the satisfaction or pleasure consumers derive from the consumption of consumer goods is called utility.
Consumers, however, cannot have every thing they wish to have. Consumers choices are constrained by their incomes.
Within the limits of their incomes, consumers make their consumption choices by evaluating and comparing consumer goods with regard to their utilities.
*Basic assumptions about a rational consumer:
Consumers are utility maximizers
Consumers prefer more of a good (thing) to less of it.
Facing choices X and Y, a consumer would either prefer X to Y or Y to X, or would be indifferent between them.
Transitivity: If a consumer prefers X to Y and Y to Z, we conclude that he/she prefers X to Z
Diminishing marginal utility: As more and more of good is consumed by a consumer, ceteris paribus (a concept that considers all other factors remain unchanged), beyond a certain point the utility of each additional unit starts to fall.
*How to Measure Utility
Measuring utility in utils (Cardinal):
Jack derives 10 utils from having one slice of pizza but only 5 utils from having a burger.
In many introductory microeconomics textbooks this approach to measuring utility is still considered effective for teaching purposes.
Measuring utility by comparison (Ordinal):
Jill prefers a burger to a slice of pizza and a slice of pizza to a hotdog.
Often consumers are able to be more precise in expressing their preferences.
For example, we could say:
Jill is willing to trade a burger for four hotdogs but she will give up only two hotdogs for a slice of pizza.
We can infer that to Jill, a burger has twice as much utility as a slice of pizza, and a slice of pizza has twice as much utility as a hotdog.
*Utility and Money
Because we use money (rather than hotdogs!) in just about all of our trade transactions, we might as well use it as our comparative measure of utility.
Note: This way of measuring utility is not much different from measuring utility in utils.
Jill could say: I am willing to pay $4 for a burger, $2 for a slice of pizza and $1 for a hotdog.
Note: Even though Jill obviously values a burger more (four times as much) than a hot dog, she may still choose to buy a hotdog, even if she has enough money to buy a burger, or a slice of pizza, for that matter. (We will see why and how, shortly.)
*Total Utility versus Marginal Utility
Marginal utility is the utility a consumer derives from the last unit of a consumer good she or he consumes (during a given consumption period), ceteris paribus.
Total utility is the utility (as a hole) a consumer derives from the consumption of all the units of a good or a combination of goods over a given consumption period, ceteris paribus.
Total utility = Σ Marginal utilities
*The Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility
Over a given consumption period, the more of a good a consumer has, or has consumed, the less marginal utility an additional unit contributes to his or her overall satisfaction (total utility).
Alternatively, we could say: over a given consumption period, as more and more of a good is consumed by a consumer, beyond a certain point, the marginal utility of additional units begins to fall.
*Total and Marginal Utility for Ice Cream (table and graphic)
*How much ice cream does Jill buy in a month?
Some facts of life:
Limited income
In fact, consumers compare the (expected) utility derived from one additional dollar spent on one good to the utility derived from one additional dollar spent on another good.
More facts
The prices of hamburger and ice cream are market-given; the consumer cannot change the price of a good.
Jill, like any other rational consumer, wishes to maximize her utility.
The opportunity cost of one dollar spent on ice cream is the forgone utility of one dollar that could be on hamburger.
If the utility of one additional dollar of ice cream is greater than the utility of the last dollar spent on hamburger, Jill can increase her total utility by spending one dollar less on hamburger and one dollar more one ice cream.
*Hamburger or Hotdog
If based on their perceived marginal utilities Jill values a hamburger four times as much as a hotdog, but the market price of a burger is eight times the price of a hotdog, she will buy a hotdog. That is because one dollars worth of hotdogs would give her more utility that one dollars worth of burgers. That is:
MUD/PD > MUH/PH
*Utility Maximizing Rules
A rational consumer would buy an additional unit of a good as long as the perceived dollar value of the utility of one additional unit of that good (lets say, its marginal dollar utility) is greater than its market price.
The Two-Good Rule
MUI MUH
--------- = ----------
$PI $PH
*Utility Maximization under An Income constraint
Consumers spending on consumer goods is constrained by their incomes:
Income = Px Qx + Py Qy + Pw Ow + Pz Qz
While Jill tries to equalize MUx/Px MUy/ Py, MUw/Pw,. and MUz/Pz , to maximize her utility, her total spending cannot exceed her income.
For example, with an and income of $86 Jill is trying to decide how much ice cream and how much hamburger she should buy.
Jills income = 5x10 + 6 x 6 = 86
*Optimal Purchase Mix: Ice Cream and Hamburger (table)
*The Budget Line (graphic)
*An Optimal Change
Recall that to maximize utility a consumer would set:
(MUx/Px) = (MUy/Py)
If the price of one good (lets say, X) would increase, this equality would be disturbed: (MUx/Px) < (MUy/Py)
To return to equality the consumer must adjust his/her consumption. (Have in mind that the consumer cannot change prices, and he/she has an income constraint.)
What are the consumers options?
In order to make the two sides equal again, given that Px and Py could not be changed, we would have to increase MUx and decrease MUy. Recalling the law of diminishing marginal utility, we can increase MUx by reducing X and decrease MUy by increasing Y.
*Price and the Shape of the Demand Curve
The two effects of a price change:
Income effect:
Normal good (-)
Inferior goods (+)
Substitution effect
Buying less X and substituting it with Y until the optimizing condition is restored (-)
As Px increases, Qx decreases
*Consumer Surplus
The difference between what a consumer is willing to pay for an addition unit of a good and the market price that he/she actually pays is referred to as consumer surplus.
The area between the demand curve and the price (line) measures the total consumer surplus.
*Consumer Surplus (graphic)
*Consumer Surplus (graphic no. 2)
*An Alternative Approach to the Consumer Theory
Indifference curves
Definition: An indifference curve is a line drawn in a two-dimensional space showing different combinations of two goods from which the consumer draws the same amount of utility and therefore he/she is indifferent about.
Budget lines
Definition: A budget line is a line drawn in a two-dimensional space representing a certain level of income with which the consumer can purchase various combinations of two goods at given prices.
*Properties of Indifference curves
Indifference curves for two goods are generally negatively sloped
The slope of an indifference curve reflects the degree of substitutability of two goods for one another
Indifference curves are generally convex, reflecting the principle of diminishing returns and they never cross.
Those which are farther from the origin represent higher levels of utility
Indifference curves for a good and a bad are positively sloped
*Indifference Curves (graphic)
*Budget Line (graphic)
*Indifference Curves (graphic)
*A change in the price of X: Income and substitution effects (graphic)
*A change in the price of X: Income and substitution effects (graphic no. 2)
Bibliografie:
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Consumer_theory
https://www.oswego.edu/~atri/Eco101-lec/ConsTheory.ppt
Microeconomics Manual, vol. I, C. Gogoneata, B. Gogoneata
Talpalaru Lenuta
Tanase Andreea
Grupa 122 (Seria F)
Politica de confidentialitate | Termeni si conditii de utilizare |
Vizualizari: 983
Importanta:
Termeni si conditii de utilizare | Contact
© SCRIGROUP 2024 . All rights reserved